Shocks
in sentence
1003 examples of Shocks in a sentence
There is mounting evidence that monetary-policy
shocks
affect risk premia, and that this channel operates internationally as well as domestically, with sizeable effects.
Political
shocks
included Brexit and Donald Trump’s victory in the United States’ presidential election – both unforeseen by the media or political elite.
When
shocks
to the system occur, agents do not know what will happen next.
Hence Keynes gave governments two tasks: to pump up the economy with air when it starts to deflate, and to minimize the chances of serious
shocks
happening in the first place.
A lot of attention has gone into making cars and factories more efficient since the first global energy
shocks
of the 1970’s.
Another, more plausible theory is that over the past fifteen years there have been various external challenges or
shocks
that have hit the country simultaneously.
Rigid as it was, with an extensive welfare system and an over-regulated labor market, Germany was unable to react to these
shocks
and ran into trouble.
All five
shocks
constitute historical developments that are good for the world as a whole, but problematic for Germany.
Finally, Bernanke claimed that “the growth fundamentals of the United States do not appear to have been permanently altered by the
shocks
of the past four years.”
Yet they render invaluable services, in terms of preservation of agro- and biodiversity, local communities’ resilience to price
shocks
or weather-related events, and environmental conservation.
There is no safety valve in currency depreciation when the economy is buffeted by external
shocks.
Compare Argentina with another grain exporter, Australia, which has been hit by some of the same
shocks.
Argentina is vulnerable to external
shocks
such as declining agricultural commodity prices because Argentina failed to develop a diversified export sector, one in which a broad range of industrial and service sectors are internationally competitive.
When a country gives up its monetary sovereignty, its banks are effectively borrowing in a foreign currency, making them exceptionally vulnerable to liquidity shocks, like that which sparked turmoil in Europe’s banking system in 2010-2011.
With the Netherlands, France, Germany, and Italy all facing populist insurgencies – and at least the first three holding elections this year – the Brexit and Trump
shocks
have naturally provoked anxiety that the next domino to fall will be one of these EU founding members, followed perhaps by the entire EU.
These inconsistencies can be explained by external
shocks
– a point emphasized by Hideo Kobayashi in his book Post-War Japanese Economy and Southeast Asia.
Without negative external shocks, exorbitant TFP growth would have declined gradually, as the returns from institutional adjustment, reallocation of resources, and technological catch-up naturally diminished, in accordance with the convergence hypothesis.
External
shocks
also explain China’s GDP slowdown since 2007.
It is likely that TFP has declined substantially as China’s economy has slowed in response to these
shocks.
Unlike Keynesians, who focus on demand shocks, followers of the Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter view cost
shocks
as important potential catalysts for structural reform and industrial upgrading – both of which are needed to avoid falling into a low-growth rut in the long term.
Given that improving overall productivity is the best way to defend against cost shocks, the new round of structural reform should be aimed at creating conditions for economic transformation and upgrading.
On the real economic side, all the advanced economies – representing 55% of global GDP – entered a recession even before the massive financial
shocks
that started in late summer.
Emerging economies were immediately affected by credit tightening (including trade finance) and rapid declines in exports, leading to similar
shocks
there.
It needs a mechanism for temporary transfers to countries that have put their public finances in order but are hit by adverse
shocks.
It has been interesting to watch growth accelerate in the face of
shocks
such as the UK’s Brexit referendum and Trump’s election.
This makes economies significantly less vulnerable to external
shocks.
Barring unexpected shocks, I believe that China’s inflation may peak soon.
Having entered the 2008-2009 crisis with sound initial conditions (including large international reserves, budget and balance-of-payments surpluses, and highly capitalized banks), they are nowhere near exhausting their fiscal and financial flexibility – and hence their capacity to respond to future
shocks.
In particular, central banks’ behavior during the crisis has called into question whether inflation-targeting is an effective framework in the presence of systemic shocks, and, more broadly, whether it can be sustained throughout economic cycles.
And when the Fed printed mountains of money in the 1970s to try to dull the pain of that decade’s oil shocks, it triggered an inflationary surge that took more than a decade to tame.
Back
Next
Related words
Economic
External
Financial
Countries
Economy
Global
Which
Would
Their
Growth
Supply
Against
Economies
There
Crisis
Vulnerable
Inflation
Resilience
World
Could