Employers
in sentence
572 examples of Employers in a sentence
For US employers, it is much easier to purge workers from the payroll – or, as Robert Gordon of Northwestern University puts it, to toss out every deck chair – than it is for German
employers.
Germany’s labor code bars such layoffs, but German
employers
also are presumably less inclined than US
employers
to shed workers, because they have invested more in their companies’ human capital.
In France, the so-called Posted Workers Directive (which allows
employers
to pay seconded workers no more than the minimum rate in the host country) may not be implemented.
And they can promote qualities like perseverance, teamwork, and leadership – the kinds of soft skills
employers
seek in job candidates – while even supporting gender equality.
But on the few occasions when he was called in for an interview,
employers
first told him he was “too expensive” or “overqualified.”
We need an immediate contingency plan: invest to finance job training, improve educational opportunities, and, crucially, create incentives for
employers
to hire young people.
Northern Europeans with money to invest were willing to lend on extraordinarily easy terms to those in the south who wanted to spend, and ample pre-2007 spending made
employers
there willing to raise wages rapidly.
Recent reports suggest that there are more than three million unfilled job openings, and about 49% of
employers
say that they have difficulty filling positions, especially in information technology, engineering, and skilled trades.
This has fanned speculation that a “mismatch” between workers’ skills and employers’ needs is a significant factor behind the elevatedunemployment rate.
In their experiments, subjects, acting as employers, were asked to choose among types of employment contracts and then observe the outcomes when other subjects, acting as employees, responded.
The
employers
initially trusted the employees to work hard without specific incentives, and quickly learned that, without such incentives, many employees would shirk.
But the
employers
also quickly learned that the best kind of employment contract is one that offers employee not just a fixed contract, but also the possibility of a bonus, a sort of gift for good performance that is outside of any contract provisions.
Employees learned in the experiments that
employers
largely could be trusted to give such bonuses as a reward for hard work, even though no one could hold them formally accountable if they selfishly refused.
For example, in a rapidly globalizing world, people may have to leave their long-term employers, with whom they have built a sense of trust, or it may be their supervisors who will have to be replaced.
Some credit the so-called “Polder Model” of social cooperation between employers, unions and the government.
Regular full-time employees are almost impossible to sack under Dutch law, but
employers
can fire part-time workers and not renew temporary contracts when they expire.
There is an “iron law” of employment: If
employers
can’t fire workers, they won’t hire them.
An extraordinarily high proportion of the labor force - 12% - is officially classified as “sick” or “invalid” because putting a worker on disability is practically the only way Dutch
employers
have of ridding their firms of unwanted full-time employees.
The movement of workers from low to higher productivity uses - whether from firm-to-firm, sector-to-sector or region-to-region - is thwarted if
employers
do not have the power to sack.
The Dutch retain the job-killing laws that make it impossible to sack regular full-time employees, but allow
employers
to sack part-time and temporary workers.
When the French changed their labor law to mandate the 35 hour work week, heavy restrictions on the use of part-time and temporary employees by French
employers
were removed.
Upgrading skills on a large scale will require coordination among parents, educators, governments, employers, and employees, with a focus on lower-skilled individuals.
Subsidies that SaveWas France’s recent wave of protests against an amendment that would have increased employers’ freedom to fire young workers a blessing in disguise?
Advocates of greater labor-market flexibility insist that paying
employers
to hire young people is the wrong approach.
Allow
employers
to fire workers more easily, they argue, and
employers
will hire them more readily.
In the United States, the pay of less qualified workers is so meager that, if their situation is not dire, they find it emotionally difficult to keep a job for long, or they become too demoralized or distracted to be adequate employees, or minimum-wage laws make them unaffordable to law-abiding
employers.
The best remedy is a subsidy for low-wage employment, paid to
employers
for every full-time low-wage worker they hire and calibrated to the employee’s wage cost to the firm.
With such wage subsidies, competitive forces would cause
employers
to hire more workers, and the resulting fall in unemployment would cause most of the subsidy to be paid out as direct or indirect labor compensation.
People could benefit from the subsidy only by engaging in productive work – that is, a job that
employers
deem worth paying something for.
India’s huge number of daily wage workers can’t find
employers
with the cash to pay them.
Back
Next
Related words
Workers
Their
Employees
Would
Labor
Skills
People
Government
Which
Should
Wages
Between
Other
Training
Governments
Employment
Insurance
Health
Countries
While