Monetary
in sentence
5081 examples of Monetary in a sentence
For the same reasons that the global economy has become more multipolar, the international
monetary
system will become more multipolar, with several currencies sharing reserve-currency status.
Hence the Keynesian solution: use
monetary
policy (lower interest rates) and fiscal policy (expanded government spending and reduced taxes) to keep the economy from ever approaching the precipice where deflation becomes possible.
In the late 1940s, those present at the creation of the post-World War II international economic order tried to create an international
monetary
system that would (a) allow for exchange rates stable enough for producers and consumers to escape the risks of excessive and irrational exchange rate fluctuations, (b) allow countries to follow their own domestic macroeconomic policies, and (c) prevent the catastrophic panics affecting not just individual banks but whole countries that produced the destructive international financial crisis of the Great Depression.
But if those who built the post-World War II international
monetary
system worked to guard against the dangers posed by panic-driven international financial crises, why are these financial devils back?
In the US, the Bush Administration is skeptical of the stimulative power of
monetary
policy and wants bigger fiscal deficits to reduce unemployment, hoping that the future dangers posed by persistent deficits -- low investment, slow growth, loss of confidence, uncontrolled inflation and exchange rate depreciation-- can be finessed, or will not become visible until after the Bush team leaves office.
The Bear of Bretton WoodsBERKELEY – This is the season for international
monetary
conferences.
And, in early April, leading thinkers and former policymakers met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, the birthplace in 1944 of the International
Monetary
Fund and our dollar-centered international
monetary
system.
Instead, what will ultimately replace today’s dollar-centric international
monetary
and financial system is a tripolar system organized around the dollar, the euro, and the Chinese renminbi.
After all, the ultimate cause of the 2007-2009 financial crisis was the dangerous inconsistency between our multipolar global economy and its still dollar-dominated
monetary
and financial system.
The good news is that this will change over the coming decade, bringing international
monetary
arrangements back into line with economic realities.
Whether
monetary
union was necessary to accomplish that aim is debatable.
Historical efforts at
monetary
union have sometimes collapsed, and sometimes they have survived multiple crises.
The main anchor of central banks’
monetary
policy over the past 20 years was an inflation-targeting framework that developed from academic interpretation of the problems involved in targeting
monetary
aggregates.
Some econometric attempts have been made to identify long-term cycles in both inflation and
monetary
growth.
At that time, it was often argued that price spikes for petroleum or other commodities were somehow “extraneous” to the system, and not a reflection of the real basis of
monetary
policy in the industrial countries.
But the oil-price shocks that came after 1973 were in part also a response to the major industrial countries’
monetary
policy in the later 1960’s and early 1970’s.
Other commodity prices had risen rapidly in the early 1970’s, in direct response to
monetary
easing in the US and elsewhere.
Food and energy prices are more likely to be affected by
monetary
policy.
Given that food and energy prices respond to
monetary
developments, and thus are not exogenous, the concept of “core inflation” obviously becomes problematic, to say the least.
It is when we worry about relative prices that we get most angry about
monetary
policy – and when central banks seem to offer no answer.
Eurozone members facing a loss of competitiveness can no longer afford to skirt difficult but necessary reforms through a
monetary
“quick fix” that shifts the burden onto their trade partners: as always, beggar-thy-neighbor policies reward laxity and penalize virtue.
This conference has grown to be a major international event for government
monetary
policymakers, with governors or deputy governors of 34 central banks attending this year.
The US Federal Reserve is sometimes blamed for the current mortgage crisis, because excessively loose
monetary
policy allegedly fueled the price boom that preceded it.
But loose
monetary
policy is not the whole story.
Alan Greenspan, the former Fed chairman, recently said that he now believes that speculative bubbles are important driving forces in our economy, but that, at the same time, the world’s
monetary
authorities cannot control bubbles.
He is mostly right: the best thing that
monetary
authorities could have done, given their other priorities and concerns, is to lean against the real estate bubble, not stop it from inflating.
The current decline in home prices is associated just as clearly with waning speculative enthusiasm among investors, which is likewise largely unrelated to
monetary
policy.
The world’s
monetary
authorities will have trouble stopping this decline, and much of the attendant problems, just as they would have had trouble stopping the ascent that preceded it.
The framework for US macroeconomic policy changed dramatically when the international
monetary
system broke down in 1971.
The arrangement collapsed because the US did not want to tighten
monetary
policy and run more restrictive fiscal policy: keeping US voters happy was understandably more important to President Nixon than maintaining a global system of fixed exchange rates.
Back
Next
Related words
Policy
Fiscal
Policies
Union
Economic
Would
Central
Which
Financial
Inflation
Rates
Growth
Countries
Interest
Their
Banks
Global
Economy
Stimulus
System