Lending
in sentence
1319 examples of Lending in a sentence
For banks to start
lending
again, even more intervention may be needed.
One possibility is that they worry about borrowers’ credit risk, though this would have to be extremely high to justify the complete cessation of long-term
lending.
But the many central bank
lending
facilities that have been opened around the world should assuage these concerns, especially for large and well-capitalized banks.
Anticipating the prospect of such future fire sales (of loans, financial assets, or institutions), it is understandable that even strong banks will restrict their
lending
to very short maturities, and their investments to extremely liquid securities.
For others, low prices would be a tremendous buying opportunity, whose prospective return far exceeds returns from
lending
today.
Any voluntary resumption of
lending
will necessitate reducing both fears and potential opportunities.
Both effects can lead to increased trade in illiquid assets today, and unlock lending, though this outcome may require significant government outlays.
One problem is that the public’s appetite for a bailout of the unregulated and hemorrhaging “shadow” financial system, consisting of institutions like hedge funds and private equity firms, is rightly small, yet it too can serve to hold back bank
lending
if a large proportion of the distressed assets are held in weak institutions there.
Unless the regulated financial system is systematically audited, with weak entities stabilized through capital injections, asset purchases, or mergers, or liquidated quickly, the overhang of distressed institutions will persist, constraining
lending.
At the end of a recent discussion with Andy Haldane, the Bank of England’s Executive Director for Financial Stability and a member of the FPC, I asked: What happens if inflation is high and
lending
is low?
During the pre-crisis Great Moderation, restraining
lending
through regulatory tools probably would have worked, because it was unlikely to push the economy into deflation, as hiking interest rates would have done.
The current issue is that the monetary aggregate (M4) measure of
lending
to the private sector is at its lowest level in a decade, while inflation is more than double the BOE’s target.
If the FPC lowers capital requirements to encourage lending, but the MPC raises rates to cope with inflation, banks would face competing pressures.
Looser
lending
rules would conflict with the higher cost of money.
Again, such policies would have worked a decade ago, in an environment of low inflation and rapid
lending
growth.
But, as of now, there has been very little increase in such
lending.
When global
lending
imploded, the most fragile borrowers were cut off first.
Thus, low interest rates make the problem go away, while the Bagehot rule – with its high
lending
rate for banks – would make matters worse.
The region has 23 million small- and medium-size enterprises (SMEs), accounting for roughly 90% of the private sector, but SMEs receive just 8% of total bank
lending.
The Trouble with China’s Troubled-Asset ReliefBEIJING – Back in 2009, in the midst of the global recession, China’s government launched a massive economic-stimulus package that bolstered GDP growth by fueling a surge in bank
lending.
Moreover, off-balance-sheet
lending
has helped to fuel over-investment in some sectors (especially infrastructure, iron and steel, energy, manufacturing, and real estate), leading to overcapacity and priming the economy for the emergence of bad-debt “disaster zones,” which would increase NPL ratios further.
But the Bank’s core philosophy has rested on lending, with interest, to middle-income countries and channeling the ensuing funds to the poorest countries eligible for assistance.
While
lending
is progressively thinned out and retained only for the poorest countries, the Bank must adopt the lean hub-and-spoke structure of a strategic consultancy or a “knowledge bank.”
The result will look familiar to aficionados of Japan’s banking crisis: zombie banks
lending
to zombie firms, which apply artificial pressure on viable firms, stifling their growth.
Given that the
lending
was denominated primarily in US dollars, it is subject to currency risk, adding another dimension of vulnerability to emerging-economy balance sheets.
But the extent of that
lending
is largely unknown, because much of it came from development banks in China that are not included in the data collected by the Bank for International Settlements (the primary global source for such information).
For example, data collected on a project-by-project basis by the Global Economic Governance Initiative and the Inter-American Dialog could provide some insight into Chinese
lending
to several Latin American economies.
For example, it seems that, from 2009 to 2014, total Chinese
lending
to Venezuela amounted to 18% of the country’s annual GDP, and Ecuador received Chinese loans exceeding 10% of its GDP.
Chinese
lending
to Brazil was closer to 1% of GDP, while
lending
to Mexico was comparatively trivial.
Indeed, business
lending
– particularly to small businesses – in both the US and Europe remains markedly below pre-crisis levels.
Back
Next
Related words
Banks
Their
Financial
Countries
Would
Which
Capital
Credit
Rates
Could
Crisis
Should
Money
Private
Interest
Government
Markets
While
Other
Institutions