Growth
in sentence
19851 examples of Growth in a sentence
The government has had to step in as both private investment and total factor productivity
growth
have faltered in recent years.
These days, it is public infrastructure investment that helps maintain India’s
growth
momentum.
Annual GDP
growth
is expected to remain above 4% in 2015, in a region where overall output is shrinking (by 0.3%, according to the International Monetary Fund’s latest projections).
Nonetheless, all three are examples that other countries, including developed ones, should watch closely as they search for viable
growth
strategies in an increasingly hostile global economic environment.
And GDP in some countries, like France and Sweden, grew at rates lower than population growth, implying that per capita income declined.
Emerging Markets’ Shifting Bottom LineLONDON – One truism of the last three decades is that emerging markets are a leveraged play on global growth: they outperform when developed economies are growing, but they are susceptible to sharp downturns when global conditions are less favorable.
Second, most emerging markets have moved to floating exchange rates, which help to cushion
growth
from external shocks such as unanticipated monetary-policy tightening in the United States.
As such, domestic bond markets are better insulated, which in turn allows governments to make use of counter-cyclical fiscal policies to stabilize
growth
and service debts.
For starters, monetary-policy normalization in the developed economies – a process that has now been underway for 30 months in the US – looks likely to continue at a slow pace, owing to adverse demographics, high debt levels, and weak productivity
growth.
At the same time, emerging-market
growth
should start to become less sensitive to US interest rates and the dollar,given lower external borrowing needs, the relative lack of borrowing in dollars specifically, and reduced dependence on commodity exports.
As a result, exchange-rate depreciation could mitigate the fallout for growth, particularly in countries with credible inflation-targeting regimes.
Second, weaker potential
growth
– the counterpart to lower equilibrium interest rates – has created fertile ground for populism in countries lacking robust institutions.
And populist policies will ultimately hinder
growth.
With faster global growth, exchange rates would bear the burden of domestic macro adjustments, and allow for a re-slicing of the (larger)
growth
pie through currency movements.
But with the
growth
potential now lower, political sensitivities to exchange rate-driven adjustments are more pronounced.
Worse still, such vicious cycles are difficult to break, because emerging-market currencies typically weaken when
growth
is threatened.
Now, currencies are the primary buffers mitigating the fallout on emerging-market debt and
growth.
Despite lower potential
growth
and equilibrium interest rates in developed economies, average absolute returns for emerging markets may be no lower than in the past.
Lower potential
growth
also raises the risk of populist policies, which would most likely have to be offset with higher spreads.
After World War II, the US launched the first “law and development movement” to promote
growth
and slow communism’s spread.
Ongoing private and public debt deleveraging has kept global demand
growth
below that of supply.
If anything, inflation is now falling further globally as commodity prices adjust downward in response to weak global
growth.
Germany’s fiscal deficit temporarily increased by about 2.5 percentage points of GDP during the global recession of 2009; subsequent rapid deficit reduction had no significant negative impact on
growth.
A government’s solvency thus depends much more on long-term
growth
prospects than on the current debt/GDP ratio.
Moreover, austerity has been accompanied by structural reforms, which should increase countries’ long-term
growth
potential, while pension reforms are set to reduce considerably the fiscal cost of aging populations.
Thus, the key variable for countries that had large current-account deficits, and thus are burdened today with high foreign-debt levels, is not the debt/GDP ratio, but the foreign debt/exports ratio (together with the
growth
prospects for exports).
But if the deficit countries spend less while the surplus countries don’t compensate by savings less and spending more – especially on private and public consumption – then excess productive capacity will meet a lack of aggregate demand, leading to another slump in global economic
growth.
Fourth, countries with current-account surpluses should let their undervalued currencies appreciate, while the ECB should follow an easier monetary policy that accommodates a gradual further weakening of the euro to restore competiveness and
growth
in the eurozone.
Such an outcome would cause another bout of severe systemic risk in global financial markets, trigger a series of contagious sovereign defaults, and severely damage the
growth
prospects of emerging-market economies that have so far experienced a more robust recovery than advanced countries.
Today, however, that
growth
has vanished.
Back
Next
Related words
Economic
Countries
Global
Economy
Which
Would
Their
Investment
Years
Economies
Productivity
Rates
World
While
Rapid
Financial
Annual
Could
Demand
Other