Bonds
in sentence
2285 examples of Bonds in a sentence
It is also a sought-after investment currency: Non-German investors hold about 20% of domestic German
bonds
and 1.300 bn in D-Mark assets.
Instead of easing liquidity constraints, as expected, these gains have exacerbated them, reflected in a spike in the interbank interest rate in October, when the seven-day rate soared to 5% and the yield on ten-year government
bonds
reached a five-year high.
By the time of the reforms of the 1980’s and 1990’s,
bonds
tying individuals to culture, the state, the work unit, and household-registration systems, for example, had largely unraveled.
First, investors, recognizing that the dollar is overvalued and that they are likely to suffer large losses when it returns to its fundamental value, could start selling their Treasury bonds, corporate bonds, and mortgage-backed securities.
At some point, the yields on
bonds
and mortgages will be high enough that investors’ appetite for yield will balance their fear of exchange-rate depreciation.
Chinese
bonds
remain unavailable.
The IMF could use its bond-issuing power to purchase GDP-indexed
bonds
from national governments, thereby providing the new global reserve assets with backing and interest-generating capacity, while creating an incentive for governments to issue them.
The Yale University economist Robert Shiller has long argued that national governments should issue GDP-linked
bonds
as a safer way to borrow, but convincing them has been difficult.
But if governments and central banks are serious about identifying alternatives to the dollar and the euro, now is the time to start – and GDP-linked
bonds
are the place to look.
By cultivating a high degree of morale and proficiency, we strengthen the
bonds
between the peoples of Japan and recipient countries.
If the status quo is ultimately unsustainable, why are markets so supremely calm, with ten-year Italian government
bonds
yielding less than two percentage points more than Germany’s?
The Fed introduced quantitative easing – buying large quantities of long-term
bonds
and promising to keep short-term interest rates low for a prolonged period – after it concluded that the US economy was not responding adequately to traditional monetary policy and to the fiscal stimulus package enacted in 2009.
The Fed’s chairman at the time, Ben Bernanke, reasoned that unconventional monetary policy would drive down long-term rates, inducing investors to shift from high-quality
bonds
to equities and other risky securities.
Japan, meanwhile is running a 10%-of-GDP budget deficit, even as growing cohorts of new retirees turn from buying Japanese
bonds
to selling them.
More controversially, the ECB needs to increase its purchases of Italian
bonds.
Unless yields on those
bonds
fall to German levels, there is no way that Italy’s debt arithmetic can be made to add up.
In order to mitigate the risk associated with these debt-funded loan purchases, the PBOC guaranteed the AMC
bonds.
In order to mollify investors in the face of increased default risk, China’s government might force commercial banks to strengthen their balance sheets through collateralization or to swap defaulted loans for new bonds, backed by China’s foreign reserves held in US Treasuries.
First, the authorities can issue
bonds
to raise the funding needed to recapitalize the banks.
Sunstein and Thaler would have the employer choose a default option that works for most people, such as 60% in equities, 30% in bonds, and 10% in money-market funds.
It can raise these funds by issuing long-term
bonds
using its largely untapped AAA borrowing capacity, which will have the added benefit of providing a justified fiscal stimulus to the European economy.
This could be added to the amount of long-term
bonds
issued to support asylum-seekers in Europe.
French banks, which were overly exposed to southern European government bonds, were key beneficiaries of the rescue packages.
Even the European Central Bank chipped in, buying government
bonds
of over-indebted countries, using a loophole in the Maastricht Treaty and overruling the Bank’s German representatives.
In order to overcome the no-bailout clause, Sarkozy and other European leaders dramatized the decline of southern European governments’
bonds
and the corresponding increase in interest-rate spreads.
By formally proclaiming a systemic euro crisis – when in fact there was only nervous market reaction concerning a few European countries’ government
bonds
– they could invoke Article 122 of the Union Treaty, which was intended to help member countries in the event of natural disasters beyond their control.
This is odd, because effects on consumption from changes in financial wealth (stocks and bonds) are small.
It could issue its own SDR-denominated
bonds.
They would pay a price, since investors in these
bonds
would initially demand a novelty premium.
Back in the 1970’s, there was some limited issuance of SDR-denominated liabilities by commercial banks and SDR-denominated
bonds
by corporations.
Back
Next
Related words
Government
Interest
Their
Would
Which
Banks
Rates
Countries
Investors
Could
Long-term
Issued
Other
Financial
Market
Sovereign
Markets
Assets
Governments
Purchases