Asset
in sentence
1608 examples of Asset in a sentence
It’s no secret that the collapse of
asset
bubbles carries massive financial and social costs.
Lack of confidence in Russian policymaking is the main reason for capital flight, low domestic
asset
prices, declining investment, and an economic slowdown that the Crimea crisis will almost certainly cause to accelerate.
The resulting “Blue Bond” (named after the color of the European flag) would be an extremely safe and highly liquid asset, comparable in volume to United States T-bills, thereby helping the euro’s rise as an international reserve currency and ensuring low refinancing costs for the bulk of eurozone debt.
Lack of opportunity means that its most valuable
asset
– its people – is not being fully used.
How can an enterprise being restructured, say, find a way to issue securities for financing if it cannot meet conventional standards such as profitability and net
asset
value, as required by the Company Law and the Securities Law?
Rent, broadly defined, is income derived solely from the ownership and control of an asset, rather than from innovative, entrepreneurial deployments of economic resources.
Nor, therefore, is their interest in housing as a major speculative investment
asset
likely to change.
It also involves, crucially, importing an essential intangible asset: knowledge.
This was and is the result of an
asset
bubble fueled by excessive leverage and by the massive transparency issues associated with complex securities and derivatives that were supposed to spread risk, but instead mainly increased the systemic risk already present with excess debt.
Absent the willingness of large developing countries to run trade surpluses and high savings rates relative to investment, the
asset
bubble in the US – leading to a rise in domestic consumption and a fall in the savings rate – would have triggered inflation and higher interest rates.
That would have put a partial brake on growth in
asset
prices, raised savings, reduced investment, and probably lowered the trade deficit.
Thus, the main reason “to take away the punch bowl” was no longer a surge in consumer prices, but a surge in
asset
prices.
It is difficult for central bankers to ignore that the financial sector stands to benefit enormously from a rise in
asset
prices.
Savings in the household sector declined and leveled off at about zero, as low interest rates led to over-leveraging, an
asset
bubble, and an illusory increase in wealth.
Though mean reversion is not a scientific law, there has never been an occasion when rising
asset
prices did not eventually return to their long-run average.
All the real work in corporations is done by skilled immigrants;Ivy League colleges have adopted the names of their Asian counterparts in order to survive; the economy is beholden to China’s central bank; and “yuan-pegged US dollars” have replaced regular currency as the safe
asset
of choice.
To the extent that continued currency-market volatility spills over into other markets – and it will – the imperative for stronger economic fundamentals to validate
asset
prices will intensify.
In addition, the Fed hopes that lower long-term interest rates will push up
asset
prices, giving households more wealth and greater incentive to spend.
Instead, excess liquidity and fresh
asset
bubbles could emerge in the world’s financial and housing markets, impeding, if not torpedoing, growth.
Silence can be presumed to be tacit acceptance that rapid increases in long-term
asset
price are warranted.
The Irresistible Rise of the RenminbiSEOUL – By the end of this year, the International Monetary Fund will decide whether the Chinese renminbi will join the euro, the Japanese yen, the British pound, and the US dollar in the basket of currencies that determines the value of its international reserve asset, the Special Drawing Right (SDR).
But the high rate of
asset
inflation in Hong Kong is due partly to an undervalued currency, set at HKD7.8:$1 since 1983 (though allowed to trade within a narrow band between 7.75 and 7.85 since 2005).
Market forces have set the real effective exchange rate by jacking up
asset
prices.
These policies boosted
asset
prices and economic growth, while preventing deflation.
Then they continued to suppress interest rates and the yield curve, elevating
asset
prices, which boosted demand via wealth effects.
Central banks’ unconventional monetary policies – namely, zero interest rates and massive
asset
purchases – were put in place in the depths of the 2008-2009 financial crisis.
According to the Bank for International Settlements, central banks’ combined
asset
holdings in the major advanced economies (the US, the eurozone, and Japan) expanded by $8.3 trillion over the past nine years, from $4.6 trillion in 2008 to $12.9 trillion in early 2017.
That implies a $6.2 trillion injection of excess liquidity – the difference between the growth in central bank assets and nominal GDP – that was not absorbed by the real economy and has, instead been sloshing around in global financial markets, distorting
asset
prices across the risk spectrum.
A combination of falling oil and primary commodity prices, an over-ripe business cycle, and the Fed’s announcement of its intent to start “tapering” its
asset
purchases brought the decade-long boom in many emerging markets to an end.
Of course, advanced-country central banks hope such
asset
inflation won’t appear at all, because inflation is being suppressed by temporary supply shocks, and thus will increase as soon as product and labor markets tighten.
Back
Next
Related words
Prices
Markets
Financial
Rates
Bubbles
Purchases
Which
Interest
Would
Their
Banks
Growth
Economy
Policy
Economic
Monetary
Credit
Capital
Could
Central